Accessory Dwellings

A one-stop source about accessory dwelling units, multigenerational homes, laneway houses, ADUs, granny flats, in-law units…

Do ADUs provide affordable housing?

This might be the “deepest” post in my whole series about research and policy on accessory dwelling units.   Though ADUs and affordable housing are often mentioned in the same breath, a closer look at this pairing seems to demonstrate a weakness, not in one policy position or another, but in the whole discussion about affordable housing itself.   It takes some work to see how ADUs even fit.

Ultimately, I feel the evidence shows ADUs have tremendous potential for creating  reasonably priced housing.  Studies in two cities indicate that, without any regulation or subsidy, 15-20% of ADUs are occupied for rents that are zero or far below market rates.  But governments and activists need to take time to understand how this form of development is unique.   In particular, it is a mistake to assume that the homeowners who create ADUs have the same skills and goals as professional developers.

But that’s jumping to the conclusion.  Let’s start at the beginning.

Pretty much everybody in America seems to agree that affordable housing is a profound need.  In areas that are gentrifying (e.g. Portland), are dominated by Silicon Valley money (say, San Francisco), or are vacation getaways for the wealthy (say, outer Long Island), residents are getting priced out and leaving. There’s a certain irony to the process, in that sometimes these are the same kind of people that made the place interesting and attractive in the first place. This leaves the area filled with a narrower range of richer people, which might be a little less interesting.

Practically every argument in favor of ADUs touts affordable housing as a likely benefit.    It’s frequently assumed, even by opponents, that ADUs are affordable housing.  For example, a NIMBY-style argument would be that ADUs could bring in undesirable low-rent characters that will bring property values down.  At least one local government (Davis, California) believes the affordability argument enough to resolve that ADUs will automatically qualify as partial contributions towards regional affordable housing goals.  Is that a fair assumption?

It’s hard to test, because “affordable housing” can mean a lot of different things. Are we talking affordability for the renter? For the owner? For the government? Are we talking rents, or construction costs?  There is no avoiding it — we MUST get into the weeds to have a meaningful discussion of this topic.

In general parlance, “affordable housing” just means housing that has a price that is manageable in relation to income.  No numbers or statistics are attached to this, but most people get the general sense of it.

However, to people in government and housing advocacy, “affordable housing” means something much more specific.  It refers to a particular set of subsidized rent programs, and the associated institutions and housing developments that take part in those programs.  Renters pay some income-adjusted sum of rent to the landlord, and the landlord often receives government subsidies for the renter on top of that.  The rules are complex, and the landlords are necessarily institutions (some non-profit, some for profit) who are willing and able to deal with that complexity.

The culture of subsidized housing rules, experts, and institutions is large enough it is possible to speak of an “affordable housing industry” , and this industry sometimes seems synonymous with affordable housing in a more general sense.

But are those programs really the only way housing can be made affordable, the way that a regular person would understand that word?

ADUs are certainly one intriguing possibility, but they don’t fit into the institutional view at all.  The people that develop ADUs are not big landlords or nonprofit corporations who are willing and able to deal with complex rules and obligations over decades.   Though there is occasional suspicion that ADUs are being built by “wealthy individuals” (see the comments on this BikePortland story), in Portland, ADU developers seem to be fairly typical homeowners who worry about their own housing costs.  A first approximation suggests that ADU homeowner-developers in Portland have similar incomes to other homeowners, at least before they develop their ADUs (page 42 of my research report).  Additional income from rent is the single biggest motivation for creating ADUs (page 40), and many anecdotes communicate that income from ADU rent has helped household finances.

Advocacy for ADUs often attempts to straddle the renter-owner divide, by claiming in a general, hopeful way that both sides can benefit simultaneously.   For example, the web site of the Puget Sound Regional Council writes:

“In expensive single family dominated areas, accessory dwelling units can also provide affordable housing choices. Most communities require an ADU to be smaller than the primary home on the property, and the smaller size can reduce the rental price of the unit. Monthly rent of the unit would likely be lower than a mortgage payment for a house in the same neighborhood… For homeowners, an ADU can be an additional source of income for property owners, offsetting the cost of home ownership.”

This paragraph works in two definitions.

1) from the renter’s point of view, affordable housing means a greater variety of unit sizes (and therefore prices) in a geographic area.  For example, in a neighborhood of large single family homes that rent for $1500 or $2000/month, ADUs could add some basement apartments that rent for $700/month.

2) from the owner’s point of view, affordable housing means extra income to help offset their housing costs (typically mortgage payments and utilities).

Neither of these definitions specifies a magnitude of cost or savings which makes things more “affordable.” There also is little acknowledgement that affordability for the renter and owner could conflict.  A house with an ADU might turn out to create cost savings for both owner and renter — anecdotal reports suggest that it often does — but it’s not guaranteed.  Perhaps the owner takes an outrageous rent because they can get it (making things less affordable for the renter, but more affordable for the owner), or perhaps the owner borrowed too much to create their ADU, and both renter and owner are spending too much.

A more pragmatic, precise definition of affordability has been used in a few papers which have actually studied ADU rents.  ADU rents can be defined as affordable if they are simply less than the going market rate for similar dwellings that are not ADUs.

Construction costs might be considered in affordable housing discussions as well.  The more expensive units are to construct, the less of them will probably be made.  So cheaper units should contribute to affordable housing in nearly every sense.  When public agencies create institutional affordable housing, the construction costs seem rather high — for example $253,000 per unit for one Portland development…. much higher per unit than ADUs developed with private money.  It should be acknowledged these are totally different kinds of construction, so the high costs may be reasonable in context.  However, at such prices it seems that such projects will serve very few people. They will not be the “whole solution.”

Finally, for perspective we should note that in some places, the affordability problem may be rooted in income, not housing cost.  Housing costs might be reasonable from the view of construction expense, etc., but if local conditions encourage low wages, then the cost to rent or own could still be beyond reach.  (For better or worse, it’s not the role of this blog to solve income inequality.)

So how do these concepts of affordable housing fare when tested with whatever data is out there?

Claim or hypothesis Best answer so far Evidence and notes
ADUs provide a greater variety of unit sizes, and therefore greater variety of rents, than neighborhoods without ADUs. Very likely to be true Anecdotal reports; survey of Portland ADUs and rents (see figure below).
ADUs provide rent income that helps homeowners meet high housing expenses. Very likely to be true. Anecdotal reports; survey of Portland rents (see figure below); survey of Bay Area ADU owners.
On average, ADU rents tend to be less than rents for comparable units that are not ADUs. May be true in some places; not true in Portland. A Bay Area study found that (mostly unpermitted) ADUs rented for an average of $250, or 19%, less per month, than non-ADU alternatives (though ADUs were smaller).  However, Portland’s average rents were not cheaper (see figure and discussion below).
ADUs are created by the rich. Unlikely to be true in Portland ADU survey results about homeowner-developer motivations and income (see discussion above).
ADUs cost less to construct than institutional “affordable housing”  Probably. Comparison of ADU construction costs and stories like this one.

Another view: ADUs have a high proportion of free and ultra-low cost units

None of the definitions examined above really bring out what I believe is the most interesting way that ADUs can be considered affordable.  It is visible in the distribution of the rents residents of Portland ADUs were paying when the owners were surveyed by the Oregon DEQ:

graph of ADU rents in Portland, Oregon circa 2013

The average rent here is $765/month.  When these kind of ADU rents are compared to similar non-ADU rentals, there is no statistical difference in averages (see the research report for details).

However, the averages aren’t the story — rather, the story is the lower end of the distribution.  13% of ADUs are occupied for zero cash rent, and another 5% are occupied for <=$500/month, extremely low rents for Portland in my experience.  If you make the arbitrary rent dividing line a little higher than $500, the proportion of free or ultra-low cost units easily reaches 20%.

This figure is no fluke — a survey in the Bay Area showed a similar number.  There, 17% of (mostly unpermitted) ADUs are occupied for zero cash rent.

This is a remarkable finding, because it shows that the homeowner-developers behind ADUs are not acting like professional real estate investors.  With zero subsidy or regulation, they are choosing to receive far less than market rent, in a real estate market where many could make four figures monthly.  They are choosing to prioritize something other than financial return.

While it is no surprise that, in Portland, the great majority of these free-or-ultra-low cost units are going to friends and family, the affordability of these units is still quite real.  For example, one ADU houses a grandmother on a fixed income.  If she were not housed in the ADU, she would probably require public assistance for housing.

This suggests that governments could encourage affordable housing simply by allowing ADUs to be built.  With no regulation or subsidy, about 15-20% of the units will be affordable by nearly any definition.

All this “free” (to the government) affordable housing does come with a trade-off.  Besides the likelihood that free-or-ultra-low cost units will go to family or friends, if the owner is living on the property, the house+ADU arrangement is so small it would be exempt from the Fair Housing Act.  For this reason alone ADUs cannot be the whole solution to the affordable housing problem.

There may be a temptation, on the part of governments or activists, to “improve” the affordability characteristics of ADUs by allowing ADUs only with a long list of requirements for rent prices and/or fairness.  I feel like this would be counterproductive.

Such requirements have been tried — for example, in the Dual Unit Opportunity program, and in Santa Cruz’s public financing option for ADU developers.  Neither got a strong response or created notable numbers of “obligated affordable” ADUs.  In Santa Cruz, the homeowner-developers of ADUs chose private financing over the public program, and avoided the extra requirements.

Moreover, the many case studies on this web site, as well as comments on the DEQ’s survey of Oregon ADU owners, suggest that ADU owners cherish the flexibility inherent in the housing form.  They can choose to prioritize money-making at some times, and to prioritize other things (usually family or friends) at other times.    Restrictions in the way ADUs can be used would probably seriously discourage their creation.

ADUs are fascinating in that they are a “grassroots” style of development.  The developers are not usually professional real estate investors, but simple homeowners.  These homeowners have changing priorities and requirements, and — to the community’s benefit — do not always choose to maximize financial return.  Affordable housing is created as a byproduct of the flexibility inherent in the housing form.   Reducing that flexibility reduces the incentive to create an ADU in the first place.

So — to sum up — ADUs do create affordable housing, but not in the usual institutional way.  The affordable housing ADUs create is unlike the product of the affordable housing industry.  It is totally voluntary and unguaranteed, and the way it is made available will not always be fair.  For these reasons ADUs can never be the entire solution to the affordable housing challenge.  On the other hand, ADUs are extremely economical to construct per unit, cost the government little or nothing to allow, and — given the number of single family residences in US cities — could be incredibly abundant.

Perhaps best of all, ADUs are individualistic and creative.  All impressions are that they add, in a small way, to family and neighborhood connections.   They could be the opposite of boring gentrification — they might actually help make a place interesting enough to live in. 🙂

 

About Martin John Brown

Martin John Brown is a researcher and consultant on environment and housing. Find out more at http://martinjohnbrown.net.

17 comments on “Do ADUs provide affordable housing?

  1. Pingback: Research and policy about accessory dwelling units: introducing a 13-part series | Accessory Dwellings

  2. Pingback: Accessory dwelling units: what further research needs to be done? | Accessory Dwellings

  3. pembquist
    September 11, 2014

    I was a beneficiary of Mitchel-Lama subsidized housing while growing up in NYC. My point of view is pretty simple. The only way to have affordable housing in a free market capitalist country is to have subsidy. The type of housing is not that important. ADU’s in Portland are subsidized by having their development costs waived and by being allowed where zoning prohibits the construction of duplexes. At the same time there are no requirements for use or affordability that go along with this subsidy. The original arguments for having an ADU loophole had to do with having aging parents living with their children and such. I would like to know what percentage of ADU built in Portland have anything to do with that now. I would expect very few. Having grown up in a very dense city I do not despise density as some people do. However the conversion of Portlands East Side from an area of neighborhoods with modest housing on small 4 and 5 thousand square foot lots to a place of teardown loomer houses, dorky land use skinny houses, and yardless ADU loophole duplexes seems like a lousy unplanned way to do development and will in the future be looked back on with a little regret.

    • plaidsportcoat
      February 21, 2017

      In Santa Cruz, CA, I also believe that a tiny percentage of ADU’s are used to house someone’s “disabled adult child”. Anecdotes that I hear all day every day from tenants, as a free tenant hotline founder, indicate that ADU’s are rented at the same outrageous prices as any other unit/room in the city/county. Since there are no diligent studies done – and that is by design, I believe – my anecdotes trump the author’s anecdotal evidence. What the heck is anecdotal evidence, anyway? There is no such thing in science. ADU’s get special consideration and fee waivers – and then Greed takes over. And the elected officials passing the ordinances know it. If they have a shred of integrity, they must admit that there is no study showing that people who build ADU’s are less greedy than any other landlord in this Homeless Factory called Santa Cruz.

      • Martin John Brown
        March 9, 2017

        Hi plaidsportscoat, thanks for your comment! And thank you for your work for tenants.

        Regarding the types of evidence available, if you read the whole post, I hope you’ll see that not everything is anecdote. The graph of Portland ADU rents is from a formal, non-anecdotal study, and the post contains a link to the full report, which you can read and critique as you see fit. The post also refers to similar formal evidence from the Bay Area.

        That formal Portland study agrees with part of what you say: that the average rent in ADUs was not statistically different than the average rent in other similarly sized dwellings. However, the distribution of those values was very unusual in its bimodality. That 20% which were free or far below market rate is very very interesting. It shows that homeowner-developers are (20% of the time) choosing to not maximize income. Greedy corporate landlords and real estate investors don’t do that.

        You also make a more historical-philosophical point about the role of anecdote in science. I would say anecdote is actually central to science. Practically every new field of study starts as a single observation — like hey, look at that weird bird.

        It is the testing of hypotheses that requires diligent work. Not sure if there’s really a “design” to limit it, or just a complete disinterest on the part of the defenders of industrial-scale housing. My guess is the latter.

        Cheers, Martin

  4. Martin John Brown
    September 13, 2014

    Hey pembquist, it’s a pleasure to get such a substantial comment!

    I can help with a specific question you asked. You asked “The original arguments for having an ADU loophole had to do with having aging parents living with their children and such. I would like to know what percentage of ADU built in Portland have anything to do with that now. I would expect very few.” There is actually data on that. According to Table 24 of this report, about 26% of ADUs are occupied by family members (17%) and friends (9%).

    As far as the general topics of density and affordable housing go, maybe “subsidy” is too generic a word. As far as I can tell EVERY form of housing is created and/or used with some kind of subsidy — there are just lots of different kinds of subsidies. E.g. it’s not just section 8… there is the mortgage interest deduction for individuals, there are various fee waivers for developers, there are different property tax rates in different parts of the city, there is the existence of city infrastructure in general — everything depends somehow on something else. I admit I haven’t done the math to figure out who’s getting the best of the situation and who’s not…. if someone has, please refer me to it.

    If by subsidy you mean the institutional form of affordable housing that’s become its own kind of industry, my reservation is this: I don’t see how, given the costs of both construction and ongoing rent support, how that system could provide the sheer volume of units that is necessary. Perhaps I’m wrong — again, if anyone has done the math, I’d love to see it.

    I’m not sure I agree with your sentiment that “the kind of housing is not important.” The kind of housing might not be important from a statistical perspective, or it might not affect the general balance of housing affordability, but the kind of housing is definitely important to individuals. E.g. the grandma that lives in an ADU (I had one in mine — I guess she was part of that 17%) very likely prefers to be there, rather than in an apartment 1 block away.

    I guess the big question is — can individual preferences like that assist more sensible planning efforts, or are they doomed to be in conflict?

  5. Pingback: Summing up ADU research: are accessory dwelling units as great, or as horrible, as people say? | Accessory Dwellings

  6. Pingback: ADUs and Condos: Separating Ownership | Accessory Dwellings

  7. Pingback: Model Code for Accessory Dwelling Units | Accessory Dwellings

  8. Pingback: From Oregon: Model Code for DADUs - Smart Growth Seattle : Smart Growth Seattle

  9. Paul Fritz
    March 27, 2015

    Reblogged this on smalltownurbanism and commented:
    Here is a good article that discusses the affordability of secondary dwelling units as a follow up to my post.

  10. Pingback: Real estate rage in Portland! Or, ode on a purple shed | Accessory Dwellings

  11. Pingback: The Death of Detached ADUs in Portland and What To Do About It | Accessory Dwellings

  12. Pingback: Affordable housing policy: ADUs and other commentary – The Samuelson Condition

  13. Pingback: Will short term rentals actually reduce long term housing in granny flats? | Accessory Dwellings

  14. Pingback: Garden Suites in Edmonton: a private investment in the public good | Accessory Dwellings

  15. Pingback: ADU Permit Trends in Portland in 2017 and 2018 | Accessory Dwellings

Comments are closed.

Information

This entry was posted on August 7, 2014 by in Policy & Trends and tagged , , , , , , .
%d bloggers like this: